Who? When Where? How? Why?
Some economic perspective on benevolent behavior
By ALLEN R. SANDERSON
Whether dropping coins into Salvation Army kettles or making
public television pledges, in 2013 Americans will give more than $300
billion to charity and also volunteer countless hours. These individual contributions swamp amounts given by foundations and other
sources, and they vastly exceed what is provided comme d’habitude in
other nations.
Who and When?However measured, there is a direct relationship between educational achievement and giving. The same holds for age: the old give more than the young. Women give more than men. There is no correlation between race/ethnicity and giving. And none of these groups is immune from the business cycle.
Income itself is more complicated. It seems to be U-shaped: the poor
and the rich give more than the middle class. In a controversial2006 book, Who Really Cares, public-policy scholar and American
Enterprise Institute president Arthur C. Brooks compared giving habits
of religious conservatives and secular liberals, and came to the conclusion one might expect from the AEI, though on the whole thisvolume is thoughtful and well-researched.
Co-mingling geography, politics and religion, “red” states give more than “blue” states.
Where?Religious organizations are big recipients of charity, but it also
depends on income level: those on the lower economic rungs are more likely to give to churches and synagogues, those higher up support the arts, higher education and environmental causes.
Reducing benefits to the rich—see below—would probably decrease the total amount of giving and also change its composition.
How?Although there are the periodic food and clothing drives, charities
prefer cash. To an economist the rationale is that money doesn’t have
the deadweight losses associated with in-kind transfers. And while
volunteer activity is to be encouraged, the economist might suggest that
“donors” spend that same amount of time in the office, where presumably
their time is more valuable, and then donate these extra earnings.
(Think opportunity cost and comparative advantage.)
Why?
In The Wealth of Nations, we find Adam Smith’s famous assertion: “It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker
that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest.” Is charity just another good like beer or bread? Is giving
different than any consumption decision from which one could derive
personal satisfaction and perhaps garner some measure of social esteem?
The fact that donors usually choose the minimum contribution for
membership or award categories, and only infrequently give anonymously,
suggests that altruism is not the sole motivation.
And are the motives and marketing of charities any different than
those of Ford, Anheuser-Busch, or a cell-phone provider? Like any firm
they use resources to produce goods and services that appeal to their
customers. In fact, learning some economic principles and business
strategies would make non-profit organizations more effective.
D.C.The 16th amendment, ratified in 1913, gave Congress the right to levy
taxes on income. Four years later, Congress allowed taxpayers (who itemize) to exclude charitable contributions from their taxes.
Though the tax code and other mechanisms are rife with subventions for
activities or behaviors we may want to encourage, including supporting
sports teams, luring corporate headquarters, or home ownership, should
charity for the wealthy be one of them? (Three biggest “tax charity”
recipients are mortgage interest payers, those who receive non-taxable
employer-provided health benefits, and donors to generously-defined
charities.)
To wit: For someone in a 30 percent tax bracket, that $1,000 United
Way contribution only costs $700; $300 would have gone to the government
otherwise. But a family in the bottom 40 percent of the income
distribution that donates $1,000 to a church gets approximately $0
because it is unlikely to be paying any personal income tax at all, or
at a far lower rate, so that gift may cost close to the full
$1,000.
The U.S. has the most generous tax incentives and also the most charitable giving. Coincidence?
Down the RoadThe political left and right have proposed various tax-code
revisions—capping the amount one could deduct from an itemized list, or
broadening the tax base and lowering tax rates. Both would effectively reduce the benefits of giving, especially at the top of the income ladder.
Perhaps one might want to tailor allowable deductions to match
societal priorities—poverty v. education v. the environment v. abandoned
animals v. disaster relief v. that second home v. political parties—thus redefining what constitutes charity and then prioritizing it. Doing them all is simply not an option: the “1%ers” don’t have that much money to confiscate!
Published: December 02, 2012
Issue: 2012 Philanthropy Issue